Wednesday, December 18, 2024

"Rising Poverty" in Milei's Argentina, Where the Annual Inflation Rate is Down 98%

Click here to read the original Cautious Optimism Facebook post with comments

5 MIN READ - An Argentina inflation and poverty dispatch from the Cautious Optimism Correspondent for Economic Affairs (and Other Egghead Stuff).

Monthly inflation rate down 91% this year, annualized down 98%

As Cautious Rockers who have been following Argentina may have noticed Javier Milei is the first libertarian president of a major country in history. In his first year in office he’s closed thirteen government agencies, slashed federal spending, achieved Argentina’s first monthly balanced budget in over a decade, and is on track to post the first annual balanced budget in a century.

INFLATION

All these deep government spending cuts haven't been carried out for the sake of itself. Prior to his election the central government was running annual deficits exceeding 15% of GDP and ordering the central bank simply create monetary reserves to fill the gap and credit them to the federal government’s account (ie. print the money).

By comparison the Biden administration’s FY2024 deficit of $1.8 trillion is running at 6.2% of GDP, itself considered alarming, and America’s central bank—the Federal Reserve—is not allowed to simply create $1.8 trillion in new reserves and credit them to the Treasury’s General Account no matter how many Modern Monetary Theory devotees say so. In the United States the difference has to be borrowed using existing dollars. 

Furthermore, as the Argentine central government spent the newly created money, the reserves entered the banking system where they multiplied to even larger M1 and M2 balances via the commonplace process of fractional reserve lending which occurs in every country.

The endgame of 15% of GDP in new reserves for the government alone—multiplied over and over via commercial lending—was a 170% rise in Argentina’s money supply in the year before Milei’s election (as measured by M2).

It’s hard to compare the numbers to the USA where the Fed switched to a “plentiful reserves” floor operating system in 2008—something very different from Argentina—but we can go back to before 2008 for a more relevant comparison.

In December 2007 the U.S. monetary base (reserves plus currency) was $837 billion supporting an M2 of $7.484 trillion and GDP of $14.7 trillion. If the federal government ran a deficit of 15% of GDP ($2.21 trillion) and, like Buenos Aires, could command the Fed to credit $2.21 trillion in reserves to the Treasury General Account, the monetary base would increase 295% to $2.96 trillion. Assuming the same fractional reserve money multiplier, M2 would roughly quadruple the money supply in a single year whereas M2 in America normally tends to rise on average by 4%-6%.

Incidentally, decades of large fiscal deficits combined with an accommodating central bank explains why long-term prices in Argentina have risen 1,640,000,000,000,000,000% (1.64 quintillion percent) since 1960 compared to 977% in the United States.

The result of large, neverending deficits and money creation, along with the expectation that more inflation was still ahead prompting Argentinians to spend their money faster and faster (ie. rising monetary velocity), was the rampant inflation that preceded Milei.

But now that the budget is balanced and there is no longer need for the central bank to provide the government with new money, inflation has fallen sharply from (depending on what source you use) anywhere from 211% to 3,700% annually last year to 2.4% monthly today, itself a decline from 2.7% a month ago.

(The Argentina National Institute of Statistics and Census reports monthly inflation was 25.5% in December 2023 when Milei took office. Compounded over 12 months that translates to an annual inflation rate of 1,427%)

2.4% monthly inflation compounded over twelve months is 32.9% per year. So since taking office Milei has reduced the annual inflation rate from—according to official sources—1,427% per year to 32.9% and falling.

“RISING POVERTY”

Milei’s achievements after just one year aren’t going unnoticed domestically, and even the left-wing international press has been forced to admit his rapid progress in lowering inflation.

However he still has plenty of critics, mostly those ideologically disposed to socialism who will castigate Milei no matter what he does.

Milei, his critics say, has raised the poverty rate from 42% to 53% since taking office.

”Argentina records sharp rise in poverty,” –BBC

”Poverty in Argentina soars to over 50% as Milei’s austerity measures hit hard. Far-right president has been battling inflation by imposing steep cuts in spending, resulting in widespread poverty,” –UK Guardian

“Argentina’s poverty rate spikes in first 6 months of President Milei’s shock therapy,” -AP

“A year into Javier Milei’s presidency, Argentina’s poverty hits a new high,” -Al Jazeera

While the Economics Correspondent freely and gleefully admits a small number of the newly impoverished are now-unemployed government bureaucrats and employees who previously “worked” for the likes of the Ministry of Culture, Ministry of Social Development, and Ministry of Women, Genders, and Diversity, the reality is the poverty rate has not actually increased and more likely has come down. Milei’s policies have simply revealed the true poverty rate from the artificially lowered levels reported under previous administrations.

The reasons have to do with the poverty rate being counted based on income. As the central bank printed money that the central government gave away to the public, more recipients’ “income” rose above the official poverty line.

But with the massive inflation and price controls imposed by the government, most citizens couldn’t buy many basic necessities with their “income” due to price ceiling-imposed shortages. The inability to buy goods and services with “above poverty” income was not factored into calculating the official poverty rate—by design.

It’s not unlike saying Venezuela, with its shortages of milk, butter, meat, water, electricity, toilet paper, etc… is “lowering poverty” because the government is printing more money and handing it out to citizens.

For this point, the Economics Correspondent will defer to a most excellent comment he read online. Although Milei himself explained this phenomenon in a recent podcast interview, it’s hard for even him to beat the succinctness of this online commenter named J.J. Parson:

”The official poverty numbers went up when Milei removed price controls. But that wasn’t an increase in poverty—it simply revealed the actual poverty level which is masked by price controls.”

”When there was [a] price control on eggs, for example, nobody was allowed to sell eggs above that price. The result was they stopped selling eggs. You could not buy them. But government poverty statistics would say—based on the price of eggs and your income—you fall above the poverty line (those were fake statistics because of the price controls—they hugely undercounted the number of people under the poverty line).”

Kudos to J.J Parson, whoever you are.

The same phenomenon was recently reported with Milei’s repeal of rent control—also a price control/price ceiling. Back when rents were capped by the government more incomes were officially “above” the poverty line, but many people couldn’t find housing to rent with that money. One in seven apartments in Buenos Aires was being withheld from the market.

Not one in seven vacant apartments; one in seven of all apartments.

When Milei repealed rent control the supply of available housing tripled within months, meaning a huge portion of the capital’s available housing had previously been taken off the market. 

Those citizens who now have a roof over their heads likely don’t feel more “impoverished,” and the same calculus applies to tens of millions of Argentinians who previously may have had more money, but who were watching their money rapidly depreciate, who couldn’t buy many basic goods and services with that money, and who were perversely being classified as “above the poverty line” by the previous government.

Tuesday, December 10, 2024

A Political and Economic History of China, Part 28: The Northern Expedition of 1926-28 and Chiang Kai-shek Turns on the CCP

Click here to read the original Cautious Optimism Facebook post with comments

6 MIN READ - The Cautious Optimism Correspondent for Economic Affairs and Other Egghead Stuff chronicles the very bloody opening shot in the war between Chinese Nationalists and Communists.

Photo: from the April 12, 1927 "Shanghai Massacre." Links to more brutal photos at end of article.

By 1926 Chiang Kai-shek had gained control of the Nationalist Party (“Guomindang” or KMT) through a bloodless coup. His main rival, left-leaning Wang Jingwei, had left for France. The Soviets, who supported the Nationalists on the condition they admit the small Chinese Communist Party, felt China was not yet ready for full communist revolution and instructed the CCP to continue working with the KMT which Moscow still supported.

THE NORTHERN EXPEDITION

Given his assumption of full leadership Chiang decided the time had come to carry out the late Sun Yat-sen’s vision of defeating the provincial warlords by military force. Chiang and his new army, trained at the Whampoa Academy that he commanded, would march from Guangdong in southern China northwards, unifying the country one province at a time.

The so-called “Northern Expedition” began in July of 1926.

Chiang’s multiyear campaign enlarged Nationalist-controlled territory applying multiple strategies, each deemed appropriate for the targeted rival warlord. If a warlord felt weak and feared soldier defections to the stronger Nationalists, he would join the KMT without bloodshed.

If one warlord was fighting another, he might join the KMT in the hope their combined forces could then defeat his rival—as was the case when the “Christian general” Feng Yuxiang joined Chiang Kai-shek to battle Manchurian rival warlord Zhang Zuolin who had just handed Feng a decisive defeat.

Some warlords simply stood their ground and resisted Nationalist forces, nearly always losing to Chiang’s ever growing armies. Some battles were quite bloody and lasted several months, with KMT victories coming at considerable human cost on both sides.

Throughout the expedition the Chinese communists played their own role, organizing workers to strike, sabotage and disrupt warlord territories in the path of advancing KMT armies.

While the CCP inconspicuously took credit for these behind-enemy-lines operations, their scale was actually quite limited. Much more commonly the Communists preferred organizing worker strikes and disruptions in newly liberated KMT territory—after Nationalist armies had already conquered them.

As KMT troops fought sometimes bloody engagements to seize provincial cities and countrysides and moved on, the Communists came up from the rear and operated in a pacified environment. After Chiang’s Nationalists had done the hard work the CCP began organizing workers and peasants to strike and disrupt the businesses, farms, and economies of newly-won KMT territories.

While Nationalists were fighting and dying on the front, the Communists were recruiting workers and peasants at a dizzying pace. CCP membership, which was only about 200 at the party’s founding in 1921, had grown to several million by 1927.

Furthermore, communist activity was causing real headaches for Chinese farms, businesses, and the establishment in general. Communists were redistributing land wherever possible, “fining” and imprisoning landlords, and “canceling” debts faster than American college grads in the Biden era, all while general strikes were grinding business production to a halt.

A rift was beginning to form between the Nationalists—always a party of the established classes—and the Communists, a revolutionary party that aimed to completely reorganize society into a proletarian dictatorship. The two parties even disagreed on where to move the new Nationalist capital with Chiang preferring Nanjing and Wang Jingwei, who by now had returned from France to capitalize on the KMT left wing’s resurgence, preferring Wuhan.

THE SHANGHAI MASSACRE

As complaints poured in from Nationalist officials and businessmen from all over KMT-controlled areas, Chiang surveyed the Communists’ ballooning membership rolls and growing strength. His armies were doing the heavy lifting, liberating China from warlords often one bloody province at a time, and the Communists were moving in after the dust had settled to sow chaos and transform recently won territories into Marxist strongholds.

Thus Chiang, already distrustful of communism and the USSR since visiting Moscow a few years earlier, decided to end the Nationalist/Communist alliance. After a brief period planning his next move he launched what the CCP has ever since named the April 12 Incident—a violent purge of the CCP from the Nationalist Party.

At dawn on the morning of April 12, 1927 Nationalist troops and Shanghai gang members attacked known communist offices and hideouts all throughout Nanjing, Shanghai, and other Chiang-controlled areas. Communists were arrested and killed later in the day, many dragged out into the streets and beheaded. The number of communists killed ultimately reached into the thousands, and even communists in the left-wing stronghold of Wuhan were purged and/or executed.

Chiang was supported by establishment intellectuals and government officials who were petrified at the sight of millions of workers and peasants seizing farms and shutting down factories, sometimes violently. Business interests also supported Chiang’s purge including his old friends in Shanghai’s Green Gang who in turn provided many henchman to carry out the killings.

The Communist Party was nearly decimated with only a few key leaders escaping the purge with their lives. The Correspondent recalls reading about Zhou Enlai, who later engineered Chinese-U.S. reconciliation with Henry Kissinger in 1971, barely slipping away from the massacre.

Meanwhile the Soviets were initially undecided about how to respond. Paralyzed by what was now a power struggle between Leon Trotsky and Joseph Stalin over who would succeed the late Vladimir Lenin, the Soviets couldn’t yet bring themselves to sever relations with the KMT. 

At the same time Chiang’s son Chiang Ching-kuo, studying in Russia and semi-brainwashed by the communist environment, publicly denounced his father as an imperialist counterrevolutionary, but the Soviet Communist International (Comintern) remained unmoved. 

Years later the young Chiang Ching-kuo would regret criticizing his father and by 1975 assumed the presidency of Taiwan as one of the world’s most vocal anti-communist heads of state.

Meanwhile as the Nationalist left wing and Chiang rival Wang Jingwei floundered and the Chinese communist movement was being decimated, instructions from the Soviets reeked of delusional fantasy.

Communiqués from Stalin instructed the KMT left wing to continue seizing and redistributing land—a difficult task in itself given the havoc being wreaked by Chiang’s purge—but to leave alone land belonging to military officers. Verifying whether each plot belonged to an officer or not and disseminating instructions to peasants on the ground, all while Nationalist forces were butchering communists, was a near impossible task to carry out. Stalin also ordered a tribunal organized to punish “reactionary” officers, again oblivious to the tactical difficulties involved in identifying every officer among the confusion let alone which ones were actually “reactionaries.”

Stalin’s instructions were effectively unenforceable.

In light of the purge and unrealistic directives from an ally that seemed completely out of touch with the reality on the ground, the Chinese communists became increasingly irritated with what they viewed as counterproductive interference from Moscow. This was the beginning of many disagreements between Chinese communists like Mao Zedong and Soviet representatives like Mikhail Borodin, and the friction between CCP leaders and Soviet advisors would linger for many more years.

With the left-wing in retreat and seemingly powerless to stop Chiang’s violent purge Wang Jingwei, always the opportunist and vacillator, blamed himself for the party’s schism and announced that Chiang was right, all before packing up and moving to Europe again.

Chiang Kai-shek was once again in control of the Nationalist Party, his rival again having departed China. Most of the Communists had been wiped out. Although a few survived, their organizational framework was gone and Chiang had the support of most of China’s establishment. Frictions between what few Communists remained and their Soviet advisors were at an all time high.

The CCP would never forget April 12th and even today commemorate it as the fateful day a treacherous Chiang Kai-shek betrayed them, firing the opening salvo in what would become a 22-year on again, off again civil war.

With most of China seemingly under Chiang’s control he set out to complete the Northern Expedition, advancing further north to Beijing. In April 1928 Zhang Zuolin, the most powerful of the warlords and based in Manchuria, elected to fight but by June his army was defeated and the Nationalists integrated Beijing into their domains. Little did Zhang know that he would soon be assassinated by the Japanese that same month.

The Northern Expedition was over. Chiang had successfully reunified China’s most populated eastern provinces from Guangdong in the south to Beijing in the north. Those sparsely populated areas in the west that he didn’t control directly were still effectively subservient to him via warlord alliances and agreements.

For the first time since Yuan Shikai’s death twelve years prior it seemed China was finally unified.
=====
Links to more brutal photos of the 1927 Shanghai Massacre:

https://lh3.googleusercontent.com/BpBGEQYTA6gTHDXbxzZGQnmEgMd7p3ovk6Ieho887OxhTg8tPk7zkJsYvoHnEoGLgcstOpVbEUY_F79I2DYA-7_jpiLXbO2DNGF68g=s1200?

https://cdn.thecollector.com/wp-content/uploads/2023/11/shanghai-massacre-1927.jpg

https://i.scdn.co/image/ab6765630000ba8a4d4df39cd205c6c91f991918


Thursday, December 5, 2024

A Political and Economic History of China, Part 27: Chiang Kai-shek Rises to Power

Click here to read the original Cautious Optimism Facebook post with comments

5 MIN READ - The Cautious Optimism Correspondent for Economic Affairs and Other Egghead Stuff continues with a history of China, this time explaining the succession of Nationalist Party leadership from Sun Yat-sen to Chiang Kai-shek.

Photo: Nationalist Party left-faction leader Wang Jingwei (left) and right-faction leader Chiang Kai-shek (right).

Let’s broadly revisit the circumstances that led up to what would soon be the Chinese Republican era’s violent climax in 1926-1928.

Revolutionary politician Sun Yat-sen’s work to overthrow the Qing dynasty teetered as the country broke down into warlord fiefdoms that often controlled weak central Beijing governments.

During the “warlord era,” Japan and the USSR in particular attempted to gain influence over China: Japan by taking territory, the Soviets by offering aid under the condition that Sun’s Nationalist Party (aka. Guomindang or KMT) accept the small, fledgling Chinese Communist Party into its ranks. The Soviets intended to eventually order the Communists to subvert the KMT from within, assume power, and transform China into both a communist state and Soviet ally on Russia’s large eastern border.

Sun, revolutionary and intelligent but too trusting and often politically naïve, had no reservations about letting the Communists into the Guomindang, but his young lieutenant Chiang Kai-shek saw danger in the Communist/Nationalist alliance.

CHIANG KAI-SHEK

As China careened into the chaotic warlord era, Sun Yat-sen decided his 1911 anti-Qing revolution had gone astray and must be righted. Instead of a united, republican, modern China the country had split into squabbling fiefdoms run by greedy, corrupt warlords.

By the early 1920’s Sun was convinced his revolution needed a strong military branch to defeat the warlords and unify the country by force. He founded Whampoa Military Academy in 1924 to train party officers for both an upcoming armed campaign of unification and later to serve in the military defense of the new China.

Sun appointed Chiang Kai-shek as the academy’s commandant.

But before we get into Chiang’s Nationalist military career we should establish a little about the man himself.

First there’s the question of his name. “Chiang Kai-shek” is Chiang’s Cantonese name. Although well known in the west, you will hear China’s one billion non-Cantonese speakers refer to Chiang by his Mandarin name: Jiang Jieshi, pronounced Jee-ahng (one syllable) Jee-eh (one syllable) Shuh.

However given that his Cantonese name has been publicized in the west for nearly a century, we’ll continue to refer to “Chiang Kai-shek” in the CO China series, just as modern day history books use it even as those same books generally use the Mandarin nomenclature format.

There are a few holes in the history of Chiang’s early life. However we know he was born in 1887 in Zhejiang province, bordering Shanghai. Like many Chinese men during the time, he became anti-Qing and highly nationalistic at an early age.

Wanting to rid China of the old corrupt dynasty and create a new modern country, Chiang decided early on a military career. He enrolled in the Baoding military academy in Beijing but transferred one year later (1907) to the Tokyo Shinbu Gakko military academy for Chinese students in Japan.

In Japan Chiang met several revolutionary anti-Qing students who were determined to overthrow the dynasty and he cut off his queue, a common act of anti-Qing disobedience. He then served in the Imperial Japanese Army (1909-1911) during which time he met Sun Yat-sen and joined Sun’s Tongmenghui anti-Qing society.

After the Qing was overthrown Chiang returned to China, working within the sometimes legitimate, sometimes not business world of Shanghai to finance KMT revolutionary activities. It was here that Chiang was mentored by Chen Qimei, fellow revolutionary and leader of the notorious Green Gang, a former anti-Qing society that raised money for the KMT through the opium trade and other lucrative vices.

Chiang’s Green Gang tutelage made him a much shrewder judge of political treachery than Sun, and the gang will come up later in the story as Chiang always maintained a relationship with his old business associates.

Finally we resume our story in 1923 when Chiang moved to Guangdong, Southern China, now the KMT’s power base although Nationalist territory was isolated, surrounded by warlord fiefdoms that controlled the rest of China.

Chiang was now one of Sun’s top lieutenants, placed in charge of developing the KMT’s new revolutionary army to defeat the warlords and reunify China. Sun sent Chiang to Moscow for three months to study Soviet military tactics where he even met Leon Trotsky. However what Chiang saw in Russia convinced him neither the Soviet system nor communism itself were suitable for China. He returned home distrustful of both, his time in Russia informing his anti-communist views.

THE CHIANG/WANG SPLIT

Meanwhile the KMT’s plans were derailed by unexpected news. In 1925 Sun Yat-sen was diagnosed with gallbladder cancer and died suddenly at the early age of 58. Without Sun Chinese reunification would have to wait until the question of new leadership was resolved.

There were a few lieutenants positioned to take over Sun’s office, but the two most powerful were Chiang, who represented the “right wing” of the party, and Wang Jingwei who represented the “left wing.” Chiang was in charge of the KMT military while Wang ran ideological and propaganda affairs.

Leaning left but not fully communist and backed by the Soviets, Wang appeared the favorite to gain control of the KMT.

Fortunately for Chiang, Wang Jingwei was a fairly weak rival. In 1926, while Wang was out of the country, Chiang announced the “discovery” of a communist plot against him and forced many of Wang’s allies out of power, even arresting some officials including a few Soviet advisors. Chiang also shut down trade union organizations and strike organizers.

All that Wang could muster in response was a few words of protest before announcing his retirement from politics and moving to France, although he would reappear a few more times over the years in failed attempts to reestablish power.

Chiang then “apologized” to the Soviets and freed their officials, but retained solid leadership of the party apparatus. He had pulled off a virtually bloodless coup and assumed full control of the KMT, even preserving a cordial relationship with and continued support from the USSR.

Meanwhile moderate KMT officials were concerned about Chiang’s heavy-handed power grab, but most remained silent since he had usurped communist leadership which they had secretly wanted ever since Sun signed the KMT-Soviet alliance in 1923.

Now in full control, Chiang set out to begin the military reunification the late Sun had coveted. He would launch it from Guangdong, southern China, historically the birthplace of so many Chinese revolutions of the past. His campaign to march north and reunite the country under a single government began in July 1926 and would become known as the Northern Expedition, a subject we’ll focus on in the next chapter.

Tuesday, November 26, 2024

Per-Capita GDP: U.S. States vs G7 Countries

Click here to read the original Cautious Optimism Facebook post with comments

The Cautious Optimism Correspondent for Economic Affairs stumbled across this chart with rankings that come as no surprise.

49 of America’s 50 states produce a higher per-capita GDP (economic output) than every non-American nation of the G7. And #50 Mississippi has a higher per-capita GDP than every member except Canada and Germany.

Read on for more details, including the "no surprise" part.

The Economics Correspondent wrote last month that nominal GDP and nominal per-capita GDP are the best measure for comparing the productivity and output of nations and their people, and that’s what this chart does.

Despite all the cries that European socialized democracies, or semi-capitalist European welfare states with high taxes and heavy regulation, are just as wealthy and productive as the USA, the data say otherwise.

The results are also no surprise given data from past analyses.

Back in 2015 the Ludwig von Mises Institute published data comparing the USA and European countries but included three adjustments, all of which served as handicaps to boost the European case.

First, instead of per-capita GDP the article used per-capita income. So instead of looking at economic output the article looked at how much income citizens receive in the ostensibly more “equal” European states.

Second, the income data included all the freebies so many citizens receive in each European country like healthcare and college education, setting aside how long cancer-stricken Europeans wait in line for a chance to use their free healthcare but giving European citizens an “income” boost that Americans don’t get.

Third, the data used “median income” which addresses the criticism that U.S. “average per-capita GDP” is skewed upwards by a small number of mega-rich earners who hoard all the income from the trounced-upon masses.

The result after all these adjustments?

Median per-capita income for the United States was still higher than 22 of 25 European countries plus Australia, Canada, Chile, Israel, Japan, Mexico, South Korea, and New Zealand—basically 30 of 33 OECD countries. Even vaunted Sweden’s median per-capita income (again, including all the freebies for citizens) was lower than 38 states placing it in the poorest quartile, poorer than Georgia, Missouri, Kansas, South Dakota, and Wyoming among others.

Click chart below:

Even red-state Texas, which liberal progressives try to frame as a conservative failure, ranked higher than the same 22 of 25 European countries including Germany, France, Sweden, Finland, and the UK.

As for those three European countries with higher median per-capita income—Switzerland, Norway, and Luxembourg—they had populations smaller than Virginia, Atlanta, and Fresno, CA respectively while the United States is the third most populous country in the world after India and China.

Two also rank far higher than the United States in the Heritage Index of Economic Freedom, both placed in the world’s top five (Switzerland and Luxembourg at #2 and #5), The third, Norway, is world’s #4 largest natural gas exporter and #8 oil exporter—all for the world's #116 population, smaller than Atlanta metro.

So it should come as no surprise that when shedding the combined handicaps of “median,” per-capita “income,” and “government benefits,” and looking solely at “economic output” the USA and 49 of its states would outperform all the G7 countries.

ps. It should also come as no surprise that Washington, DC is the “state” with by far the highest per-capita GDP. Since GDP includes the dollar quantity of government purchases the nation’s capital comes out on top despite not really producing as much as most other states. Washington’s outsized role of government within its economy artificially inflates its ranking.

Thursday, November 21, 2024

A Political and Economic History of China, Part 26: The Republican Era of 1912-1928, Part 2—International Power Struggles

Click here to read the original Cautious Optimism Facebook post with comments

6 MIN READ - The Cautious Optimism Correspondent for Economic Affairs and Other Egghead Stuff continues with the chaotic Republican Era of China, this time detailing foreign influence in the power struggles of the 1910’s and 1920’s including the opening chapter of the Chinese Communist Party.

Picture: Revolutionary founder of modern China Sun Yat-sen (seated) with young military commandant Chiang Kai-shek (standing, center).
After General Yuan Shikai’s death in 1916, Republican China was unable to establish an effective government. Not only was the central government’s army lacking to counter the regional warlords’ private armies, internal republican bickering and infighting produced fourteen different presidents in the twelve year period of 1916-1928.

And not only warlords vied for power in this era. Foreign governments exerted their own malign influence over China.

JAPAN

As most people know Japan invaded Manchuria in 1931 and China proper in 1937. But the fascist Japanese government had been planning these invasions for a long time, even positioning themselves for an eventual conquest of China back in the 1910’s.

As China descended into post-Qing chaos, Japan attempted to exert influence and gain pre-invasion footholds.

At the outbreak of World War I Japan declared war on Germany in a classic display of realpolitik. Tokyo couldn’t have cared less about Europe, instead leveraging entry in the war to expand its presence in Asia. 

While Germany was bogged down in the trenches of Europe, Japan invaded and occupied German territory in China’s Shandong Province. Japan also grabbed a few German territories in Micronesia which would gain notoriety during World War II: the Marshall Islands (including Kwajalein), the Carolines (including Truk), and the Marianas (Guam, Saipan, Tinian).

By making token contributions to the allied effort Japan successfully gained a permanent seat at the League of Nations. The Japanese also bribed a regional Chinese warlord into granting sovereignty over Shandong province, followed up by tacit albeit lukewarm consent from the allies at Versailles. Chinese government representatives only put up weak objections.

But the handover of Shandong unexpectedly triggered a watershed event in Chinese history: the May 4th movement of 1919.

Everyday Chinese were so incensed over their loss of territory to Japan that mass demonstrations began throughout the country. In what’s now considered the birth of modern Chinese nationalism, protestors criticized Japan, the Versailles Treaty, the allied powers, and the Chinese Republican government itself. Disillusioned with the continuing failure of China’s elites, the masses turned away from traditional Confucian deference to intellectuals, and Chinese who had formerly considered themselves “Sichuanese” or “Shanghainese” or “Cantonese” unified in a populist mindshift to being “Chinese.” 

The western powers, surprised at the level of outcry from the Chinese public, forced Japan to relinquish sovereignty over Shandong which was promptly returned to China.

However much of the social die was now already cast. Along with rejecting much of Confucian traditionalism many young Chinese were now searching outside the country for new philosophy, new ideas, and new direction.

One of the many strange and foreign ideas that found growing acceptance among everyday Chinese was the anti-imperialist credo of Marxism. In 1921 a small group of radical revolutionaries, anti-imperialist and drawn to Karl Marx’s promises of utopian equality and total peace, founded the Chinese Communist Party in Shanghai with the 27-year old Mao Zedong representing his native Hunan province.

RUSSIA/THE USSR

Vladimir Lenin and the Bolsheviks seized control of the Russian Empire in 1917 and, after a centuries-long history of border and territorial disputes in Manchuria and Xinjiang, watched with interest the chaos unfolding in China just four years later.

While attempts at establishing republican government in China floundered, none of the formerly imperialist western powers stepped up to help. Some European governments were concerned about continued reparations payments from the now defunct Qing dynasty. 

The extent of their interest in Chinese stability was usually limited to a desire to avoid total national disintegration, for that would put their business investments at risk. However, western powers also disliked the idea of a tightly unified China that might one day find the strength to say no to outside demands.

Sun Yat-sen, who by now had formed the Nationalist Party or Guomindang, looked to the foreign powers for help getting the new China on its feet, just as he had looked outside for help bringing down the Qing dynasty a decade earlier. But for the reasons just mentioned he found few takers.

The only major power that offered assistance was the Soviet Union, but as one might guess that help hardly came for free.

The Lenin government, concerned that capitalist countries might attack Russia to destroy the communist revolution in its fragile infancy, found the idea of a communist ally on its huge eastern border appealing. Ideologically Lenin also saw China as a fraternal century-plus target of capitalist imperialism and was sympathetic to Sun’s revolution to throw out the foreign Qing rulers.

Given Sun’s need for help, negotiations between Soviet and Nationalist officials led to an alliance in 1923. In exchange for financial and diplomatic assistance, the Nationalists agreed to welcome Soviet advisors who restructured the party with more rigorous discipline.

The Soviets also attached a condition for aid which would change the history of China: The Nationalists must agree to an alliance with the Chinese Communist Party and allow the small upstart movement into their ranks. 

After all, both the Nationalists and Communists were anti-Qing, both were anti-imperialist, and both wanted to build a new, modern China. To Sun, the Communists seemed harmless and possibly even a good fit.

In secret Moscow believed one day they would order the Chinese communists to usurp Nationalist leadership, take over the party for themselves, and transform China into a communist state. However the Soviets felt China wasn’t yet ready for communism—not having first passed through the key Marxist historical stages of capitalism and socialism—and for now ordered the CCP to simply cooperate with the Nationalists.

The Chinese communists, as the Soviets would later learn, had their own timetable which we’ll discuss in an upcoming chapter.

Sun agreed to integrate the Communist Party into the Nationalist Party, but one of his top young protégés—the commander of the party’s military wing—viewed the Communists with suspicion, although he didn’t yet possess the power or rank to act. 

This shrewd lieutenant was Chiang Kai-shek.

We’ll get more into the Nationalist/Communist alliance and Soviet influence ending with the 1949 communist victory later, but on a final note it’s important to contrast Sun and Chiang’s views on alliances and power which in turn informed their different views on the Communists.

For all his strengths, Sun was at heart an intellectual and often politically naïve. By contrast Chiang Kai-shek, mentored in his youth by one of Shanghai’s most notorious anti-Qing societies-turned-organized crime syndicate (the Green Gang), held more cynical and realistic views.

A story recounts how in 1920 Sun entered into another alliance with Guangxi warlord Chen Jiongming. Chiang, still a young protégé, calculated Chen had much to gain by betraying the Nationalist alliance and repeatedly warned Sun of the danger but was ignored. Sure enough Chen rebelled, shelling the Nationalist Guangdong headquarters in 1922 with Sun barely escaping with his life. Chiang, always loyal, made speed from Shanghai to rescue his master and they spent several weeks hiding out on a small riverboat during which time Chiang’s stock rose in Sun’s eyes.

Chiang viewed the communist alliance with similar suspicion. He believed, correctly, that the Communists would attempt to subvert the Nationalist Party from within and take over, but for now Sun sleepwalked into accepting Soviet demands, oblivious to the danger that his young disciple foresaw.

In the next installment we’ll discuss growing tensions between Nationalists and Communists against the backdrop of the campaign to finally reunify China.

Wednesday, November 13, 2024

A Political and Economic History of China, Part 25: The Republican Era of 1912-1928, Part 1—Domestic Power Struggles

Click here to read the original Cautious Optimism Facebook post with comments

6 MIN READ - With the 2024 campaign and election over, the Cautious Optimism Correspondent for Economic Affairs and Other Egghead Stuff restarts his history of China series, picking up with the chaos that ensued after the fall of the last imperial dynasty in 1911.

Attached picture: Rough outline of regional Chinese warlord control in 1925. Blue areas are controlled by Sun Yat-sen’s revolutionary Nationalist (Guomindang or GMD) party.

In July we left off with the tireless efforts of Chinese revolutionary Sun Yat-sen whose work played a role in the collapse of the Qing dynasty (1644-1911).

The Qing’s disintegration was sudden and unexpected. Sun was himself in Denver, Colorado raising money when it happened and quickly returned to China to formulate a new, more modern government to fill the power vacuum that had so abruptly appeared.

Despite his revered place in history today, it’s important to understand that in 1911 Sun was only one of many players working to topple the Qing, an alien dynasty of outsiders that had fallen out of favor with its ethnic Chinese subjects. Upon Sun’s return to China he was still not very well known. Among the candidates to lead a new China Sun was viewed as lacking the strongman character needed to rule a provisional government during such a precarious time.

After deliberation among revolutionary leaders a fairly obvious choice was made to assume that role, at least temporarily: General Yuan Shikai. 

Sun assented to Yuan's presidency for the same reasons.

YUAN SHIKAI

Yuan Shikai is a shady figure in Chinese history and likewise loathed in modern China. Dubbed the “traitor general” for:

1) Betraying the young emperor Guangxu’s plans to reform China in 1898 by ratting him out to his aunt, the powerful empress dowager Cixi. Cixi then arrested Guangxu and later had him poisoned, and

2) Betraying the anti-Qing Xinhai revolution, something we’re about to get to.

A little background on Yuan.

During the great Taiping rebellion of 1851-1864 the scholar-general Zeng Guofan commanded Qing forces so skillfully that he was awarded control over most of the postwar imperial army. Zeng’s protégé, Li Hongzhang, assumed that role shortly after when the aging Zeng, who had been brought out of semi-retirement during the civil war, called it quits.

Over the next four decades the Qing weakened and Beijing increasingly lost its ability to govern the country. Subsequently regional military governors, generals previously appointed by Zeng and Li, took greater control of their provinces. By the time of the Qing’s collapse Li’s protégé, the aforementioned Yuan Shikai, was now general of the most powerful armies based in Beijing and it was only he who could keep the semi-autonomous provincial generals (later dubbed “warlords”) in line.

So in 1912 most anti-Qing revolutionary leaders viewed Yuan as the only man strong enough to prevent China from breaking up into military fiefdoms and he easily won appointment as provisional president by vote of the new provisional senate.

In theory China would become a republic with a democratically elected parliament and president sharing power. The Nationalist Party, or KMT (known as the “Guomindang” in mandarin) held the most seats in parliament with Sun Yat-sen as party leader.

However before long it became clear Yuan was interested in neither democratic government nor power sharing. He attempted to dissolve the republican house of representatives and senate, leading to clashes with the Nationalists and other democratic reform-minded parties. In response Yuan consolidated his power by granting even more autonomous powers to his regional military allies in return for support.

In 1915 Yuan made it official by arranging a puppet council vote to “offer” him the emperorship of China which he “accepted” as head of a new dynasty. He quickly ordered jade seals and imperial robes for himself.

It seemed after all the hard work and sacrifice to rid China of the Qing dynasty the imperial monarchy had returned.

But the political backlash against Yuan’s new dynasty was so great that even many of his warlord allies protested. A few provinces outright rebelled.

Surprised by the opposition Yuan delayed his coronation ceremony over and over again, attempting to appease his detractors enough to eventually carry through with his ascension, but after just 83 days officially as emperor he “abdicated” and restored the republic—in part due to growing revolts but also because his own health was failing. 

Yuan died just three months later of uremia.

China had dodged a restoration of the dynastic system, but Yuan’s death would leave behind an even larger power vacuum than the one he had filled. Now there was no obvious choice to control the warlords and China began its descent into regional and provincial chaos.

Once again, in theory a democratically elected republican government in Beijing—composed of a parliament and president—would run China. But in practice the republican government had no effective power to control the autonomous warlords and their personal armies.

Further complicating matters was internal bickering among republican politicians and a few political assassinations. Without clear direction no elected president held power long enough to challenge the warlords let alone build a new China, and the Beijing government often became a puppet of the strongest militarist warlord cliques. By one count after Yuan’s death Republican China had fourteen presidents from 1916 to 1928, the year Chiang Kai-shek officially became president and held power until the communist civil war victory in 1949.

WARLORDS

Hence the 1916-1928 period is famously known as the “warlord era.” Multiple generals enjoyed regional authority over counties, provinces, and in some cases multiple provinces. Most craved expansion of their fiefdoms, some signed fragile alliances with one another, and others went to war.

The one constant under all warlords was general suffering of the common people. Warlords raised funds for their mini-empires by imposing direct taxation—often precocious and excessive—on the peasants. To the common Chinese villager it seemed that things hadn’t changed much from the Qing dynasty. Instead of corrupt regional Qing officials it was now regional warlords who squeezed them.

The many warlords also made for a colorful cast of characters, some whose nicknames found their way into the western press. For example there was Zhang Xun, known as the “Pigtail General” for his Qing loyalties. Zhang wished to restore the Qing monarchy and ordered his troops to retain their queues.

Then there was the “Christian General” Feng Yuxian, who converted his troops to Christianity and baptized them with a fire hose.

One of the worst warlords was Zhang Zongchang, dubbed the “Dogmeat General” because of his taste for a Chinese tonic named “dogmeat” and penchant for playing the Chinese gambling game known as “eating dogmeat.” Time Magazine called Zhang Zongchang “the basest warlord” for his brutality, eccentric personality, and lavish lifestyle—financed by the peasants he crushed under repressive taxation.

Given that the warlords enjoyed de facto control over their regions, business interests—both domestic and foreign—were forced to deal with them which usually meant paying regular bribes to retain their investments and run their operations.

The most consequential warlord-foreign investment relationship was between Japan and perhaps the most famous and powerful of all the warlords: Zhang Zuolin, who enjoyed control over all three provinces of Manchuria while engaging in power-sharing agreements with Beijing.

During the 1920’s Japan made significant investments in Manchuria, the offshoot of expelling Russia during the Russo-Japanese War of 1905. Zhang's army received financial backing from the Japanese in exchange for allowing the construction of Japanese railroads and factories.

Japan, which history now records had its eye all along on the outright conquest of Manchuria, felt Zhang was too formidable an obstacle to their plans and arranged his assassination by exploding a bomb under his railcar the evening of June 4, 1928. From there the Japanese attempted to install his more malleable, opium-addicted son Zhang Xueliang to replace him. However, the Japanese were soon surprised at the son’s resolve when he shook off his opium habit, assumed his father’s place with authority, and put up a great deal more resistance than they had anticipated.

A decade later Zhang Xueliang, serving as a general in Chiang Kai-Shek’s Nationalist army, would kidnap his own boss in an incident with huge implications for China’s future, a subject we’ll get to during World War II.

In the next installment on the Republican Era we’ll look at foreign interference during China’s early road to modernization.

Friday, October 18, 2024

Inflation Has Repudiated $5 Trillion of U.S. Government Debt Since Biden's Inauguration

Click here to read the original Cautious Optimism Facebook post with comments

3 MIN READ - A national debt update from the Cautious Optimism Correspondent for Economic Affairs and Other Egghead Stuff.

Cautious Optimism regular Keith Shapiro (aka. K-Shap) commented a few weeks ago that “governments love inflation.”

He’s absolutely right and here’s a prime example of why.

This November the federal government will have repudiated $5 trillion of its debt since Joe Biden took office, but without paying the debt down by even a penny. It will all be through the magic of inflation.

Here’s the fairly simple math.

1) Starting with the arbitrary baseline of January 2021, the national debt was $27.75 trillion at the time.

Since January 2021 the CPI index has risen 19.9%—diminishing the dollar by 16.6% of its value. Hence, $4.61 trillion of the $27.75 trillion debt has been wiped out due to the watered down value of our money.

(We are using official government CPI here for what it’s worth, so apply your own numbers which will certainly mean higher inflation and ultimately far more than $5 trillion of debt erased)

2) In 2021 the federal government added another $1.87 trillion of debt and the dollar has lost 10.3% of its value since then.

Another $193 billion of debt erased.

3) In 2022 the federal government added another $1.80 trillion of debt and the dollar has lost 4.6% of its value since then.

Another $83 billion of debt erased.

4) In 2023 the federal government added another $2.58 trillion of debt and the dollar has lost 1.6% of its value since then.

Another $42 billion of debt erased.

We’ll skip what debt has been added so far in 2024.

So add $4.61 trillion + $193 billion + $83 billion + $42 billion and inflation has helped the Treasury renege on $4.93 trillion of debt.

These numbers are as of September 2024. Unless the government borrows nothing in the next two months and inflation reaches zero as well, the amount of debt relief the government has granted itself will exceed $5 trillion by November.

As a reminder, $5 trillion is roughly how much George W. Bush increased the national debt during his eight years in office—a figure liberals screamed bloody murder about at the time. But with less than four years of inflation the Federal Reserve has just “coincidentally helped” absolve Bush’s entire eight-year debt tab just by cranking up the printing presses.

It’s an old trick that goes back to (the oldest version the Correspondent can find) ancient Greece around 380 BC. Cautious Rockers who missed that story can go to…

https://www.cautiouseconomics.com/2024/02/economic-history-05.html

The same story repeated itself in ancient Rome…

https://www.cautiouseconomics.com/2023/07/inflation-currencies33.html

And in medieval England…

https://www.cautiouseconomics.com/2022/10/inflation-currencies25.html

And today across the entire world with modern central banks.

Governments borrow $1,000 and promise to pay it back 10 years later. But in between the economy grows 2% a year and the central bank raises prices by 2.5% a year, so 10 years later nominal GDP is 56% greater.

Assuming the government taxes roughly the same percentage of GDP in 10 years that it does today, its nominal revenues are 56% higher, making it easier to repay the $1,000.

Of course the economy really only grew 21.9% in those ten years (1.02^10). The other 34.1% of that nominal GDP growth is simply inflation and higher prices.

It’s a sweet deal for the government that finds it much easier to repay debt with considerably less valuable dollars that are more abundant when the bill comes due.

But there’s no such thing as a free lunch. So who really pays for this sweet deal? 

Savers—basically anyone holding dollars who watches their wealth debased 22.4% by the printing press.

In a longer 30 years their dollars are debased by 53.2%. Yep, cut by more than half.

This is what the Fed calls “price stability,” and what Democratic politicians pin on “corporate greed.”

And these numbers all assume a scenario of 2.5% inflation. We saw official inflation peak at 9.1% in late 2021.

The 1970’s were even worse. From 1971, when Richard Nixon broke the last link between the dollar and gold, to 1983 the dollar became 38 cents wiping out savers and retirees in particular. If the national debt ever starts to get unmanageable the Fed can come to the Treasury’s rescue in such a manner again (imagine our $35 trillion debt becoming only $13.3 trillion in twelve years), then officially announce “Sorry, it was just a small mistake on our part. We have inflation back down to about 2% so everyone should be happy now.”

And anyone who complains that “Hey, this fiat money monopoly run by the Fed is ripping us all off. We need money tied to a finite commodity like gold again” will be mocked and ridiculed by the liberal media and government economists as a pedantic neanderthal. 

Because everybody knows the only way an economy can possibly function is with a state-sanctioned monopoly that creates money at zero cost without limit, gets its power from the same government that is heavily in debt and which uses police and guns to shut down any alternative form of money while forcing its citizens to use only its crummy, depreciating currency.

Another coincidence: the government and its economists say the state monopoly issuing their constantly devaluing money is just the only version of money that will ever possibly work. We can't even think about alternatives.

Thursday, October 10, 2024

GDP Part 4: Is the Consumer Really Two-Thirds of the Economy?

Click here to read the original Cautious Optimism Facebook post with comments

6 MIN READ - The Cautious Optimism Correspondent for Economics Affairs and Other Egghead Stuff concludes his miniseries on what goes into GDP.

Gross business receipts vs. consumer spending

We’ve all heard it over and over from politicians and media: “the consumer is two-thirds of the economy,” or sometimes “consumer spending is two-thirds of the economy.” And the statistic is accepted as an article of faith by the business press while used by certain politicians and academics to minimize the importance of the business sector.

Why exactly do they run around saying this? And is it true?

As you might guess, the answer is a little complicated.

GDP MATH

First let’s cover where the “two-thirds” number comes from. You may recall reading in an earlier installment of this GDP series that Gross Domestic Product is calculated as consumption spending + business investment spending + government purchases + net exports, or:

Y = C + I + G + Nx

If we go to the Bureau of Economic Analysis webpage and break down these elements for the full year 2023 we get the following:

(C)onsumption spending = $18.8 trillion
Business (I)nvestment spending = $5.0 trillion
(G)overnment purchases = $4.7 trillion
(Nx)et exports =  -$800 billion
GDP = $27.7 trillion

Based on these figures, consumption spending is indeed 67.8% of GDP. And business investment is a surprisingly small 18.1% of GDP.

And there it is (according to politicians and the business press): proof positive that the consumer is “two-thirds of the economy.”

But is it really that simple?

PROBLEMS WITH GDP

A vocal minority of economists argue that official GDP numbers are misleading and understate the size of business investment activity. For one, salaries aren’t counted but instead only spending on capital investment for things like factories, buildings, machines, etc…

Incidentally, excluding salaries is part of the more popular “expenditure approach” to GDP, but the less-used “income approach” to GDP includes employee compensation. However we’re not going in depth into the accounting of “expenditure” versus “income” GDP in this article.

Another controversy that the Economics Correspondent would like to address in more detail is the intermediate “value added” math used in GDP.

That sounds like a mouthful, but in plain English it means this: GDP calculates business investment spending by counting only the total investment that goes into the final stage product. It doesn’t include investment spending on all the intermediate goods that work their way up the supply chain to the finished good.

A simple example might be a car. General Motors might make a steel chassis and produce its own engine and transmission for a car it intends to sell. Additionally GM will have investment costs for factories and machines that help workers produce these components and assemble the car. 

GDP includes all these costs in investment spending.

However before GM bought the steel for the chassis, raw iron first had to be extracted from the earth. The raw materials company had business investment expenses of its own.

Guess what, the raw materials company’s investment expense is not included in GDP (will explain why in a moment).

The same is true for the refining company that purified it into productive metal. Its purchase of the ore and all investment expenses for its plant are not included in GDP.

Then the steel mill that combined the iron and coke incurred expense to purchase those precursors plus investment expense for the mill and furnaces. None of this spending is included in GDP either.

In economics terms, only investment spending on the final product is counted, but investment in goods produced during the intermediate stages of production which ultimately find their way into the final product are not counted.

Hence the controversy. How can business investment be only 18% of GDP when only investment spending at the final goods level (General Motors’ inputs, plant and equipment) is counted, but spending for the steel mill, the refiner, the raw ore extractor, and countless other firms that produce the myriad of precursors for wheels, tires, seating, windows, electronics, fluids, glass, etc… is not?

OFFICIALLY THE ANSWER IS…

Well the mainstream economics community has a good answer. They want to avoid double counting.

If the refiner pays $250 for a block of ore, then adds its own investment to turn it into refined iron and sells it to a steel mill for $500 which in turn combines it with other inputs and sells the steel for $750, economists don’t want to add $250 + $500 + $750 = $1,500.

To count $1,500 in business investment expense would count the $250 paid for the block of ore three different times as it's sold once to the refiner, a second time to the steel mill, and a third time to GM.

The same for the refined iron. Economists don’t want to count its $500 twice: once when sold to the steel mill and a second time when the steel is passed on to GM.

On and on, they say, down the production chain… double and triple and quadruple counting could inflate the numbers. By the time the chassis is produced for, say, $1,000 (the Correspondent is guessing, he doesn’t really know how much a chassis costs to produce), the chain of businesses could have “invested in” the $250 block of iron ore three or four times. 

In economics terms the logic is this: all the investments by intermediate stage companies will ultimately be reflected in GM’s final product: the car. GM paid, say, $20,000 for all inputs (there’s your single counting for intermediate stage investments), added $10,000 more of its own investment spending and, after a few transfer costs like interest on debt and taxes, sold the final product for a profit at $35,000.

With traditional GDP only the investment inputs added by GM—plus all the inputs from intermediate firms which are reflected solely in the prices GM, and only GM, paid suppliers for those inputs at the last stage—are counted using this math. There is no double counting of investment.

VERDICT?

As mentioned before, the mainstream economics community accepts the “don’t double count” logic pretty much unquestioningly.

The Economics Correspondent agrees with the logic too, but believes that leaves us with a not fully satisfying number that can still be misleading in other ways.

In the affirmative, yes, the investment dollars for a block of iron shouldn’t be multiplied two, three, four, or five times just because it passes through the hands of several firms.

Where the math gets misleading is it completely understates the total amount of business activity and gross investment spending that goes on in the economy. The math looks as if GM is the only company spending any money when in fact there are countless firms “behind” GM that are collectively spending even more and also employing a lot more people.

It also understates the impact on the economy of disruption in the business sector. If investment spending fell by 5% then according to the standard formula just 5% of 18% is a 0.9% fall in GDP: a blip on the radar.

But a 5% reduction in all (gross) business spending is a much larger number. In the real world the scope of business losses, bankruptcies, and idling of workers would be enormous, far outstripping the suggested 0.9% slump (see attached chart during 2008 and 2020 recessions).

Why? Because there are a whole lot more dollars flowing through the business sector overall than the GDP model portrays.

(Also see comparative size of recessions in attached chart from economist Mark Skousen’s column: “Business—Not Consumers—Drives the Economy.”)

And let’s not even get started on how the salaries and compensation of all those employees isn’t even counted. We even noted in an earlier article that government spending on employees and contractors is considered a “purchased service” and counted in GDP, yet all those private sector salaries and other compensation are not. This makes government worker salaries look “productive” for the economy while private sector salaries are mathematically excluded.

What, private sector employee's aren't productive but government workers are?

Imagine how much larger business investment would look as a share of the economy if private payrolls were included.

There is an alternative measure of economic output that attempts to right some of these wrongs called Gross Output or GO, and in 2014 the Bureau of Economic Analysis even began including crude statistics on GO although they’re buried deep in the website and basically require a search to locate. However the BEA is tacitly admitting GO has certain advantages by putting it on their site.

Conclusion: In the first article on GDP the Correspondent said the formula is pretty good, but not perfect. Understating business activity and excluding expense on salaries are the two biggest reasons why.

In the end, traditional GDP is correct not to double, triple, and quadruple count investment expenditures as intermediate goods flow through the various stages of production, but the press should be a lot more careful when concluding from the simplified math that “the consumer is two-thirds of the economy.” 

Of course in a world where people only want to have to digest a single headline, good luck explaining the nuances of where GDP math falls short. And don’t hold your breath waiting for the media, in its present wretched form, to grasp the math either let alone not censor it even if they did understand.

Tuesday, October 1, 2024

GDP Part 3: Annualized GDP and GDP Across Different Countries

Click here to read the original Cautious Optimism Facebook post with comments

5 MIN READ - The Cautious Optimism Correspondent for Economic Affairs and Other Egghead Stuff continues his mini-series on understanding GDP.

Nominal and PPP GDP yield different results

ANNUALIZED GDP

As we continue our examination of GDP as a measurement tool, a quick word about quarterly and annualized GDP figures.

When the Bureau of Economic Analysis releases a quarterly GDP report with headlines like “Economy Grew at 3% Pace in Second Quarter,” the 3% number is annualized. That is, the economy only grew about one-quarter as fast as 3% but the BEA reports an annualized number that assumes the same quarterly rate of growth continues for three more quarters. This makes the final number easier to understand for readers.

Most people would prefer a headline that reads “grows at 3% annualized pace” than “grows at 0.75% quarterly pace.”

Incidentally the assumed growth over four quarters is compounded so technically 3% annualized isn’t quite 0.75% per quarter. If one compounds 0.75% growth over four quarters the annualized result is actually slightly higher than 3% (1.0075 * 1.0075 * 1.0075 * 1.0075 = 1.030339), or +3.03%.

Such a tiny difference may not mean much, but when dealing with larger numbers the differences can stack up, namely during the recent Covid crisis.

When the state governments shut down economies across the country in the second quarter of 2020, the BEA reported that GDP contracted by 34.3%.

We now know that’s an annualized number so one might assume the real rate of contraction for the quarter itself was 34.3 divided by 4 or -8.575%.

In fact, the quarterly contraction has to be compounded four times, so although the math is a little weird the formula is actually

(1-.343)^(1/4) = .9003

...or a quarterly contraction of -9.97%, not -8.575%.

Likewise when the economy reopened in the third quarter, the much less widely reported headlines read that GDP rose by 33.4%.

Once again, 33.4% is annualized, assuming the quarterly rate of growth compounds over four quarters total. So using our compounded math the economy really grew 1.334^(1/4) = 1.0747 or 7.47% that quarter.

Down 9.97% in Q2, up 7.47% in Q3. In one quarter the economy clawed back most of what it had lost, but not all.

OTHER COUNTRIES: NOMINAL GDP

Occasionally the Economics Correspondent will read a headline that “China has the world’s largest economy measured by purchasing power parity.”

As you might guess, this headline is pretty misleading. China does not have the world’s largest economy (although it is safely #2).

The source of confusion is that economists use two different measures of GDP, especially when comparing different countries: nominal versus purchasing power parity or PPP.

The easiest way to think of these two is:

“Nominal” is the best measure of the actual value of all products and services produced by an economy. On that measure the United States remains #1 at $28.78 trillion versus China at $18.53 trillion (IMF).

"PPP" takes nominal GDP and adjusts it for cost-of-living in each country. So while the USA might produce more stuff and more valuable stuff than China, it still costs Chinese less to live in China than it costs Americans to live in the USA.

But when comparing U.S. output to Chinese output the Economics Correspondent thinks it’s useless to work with PPP and divide by U.S. or Chinese cost-of-living. Nominal is what matters which indicates the USA still outproduces China.

To see the difference in U.S./Chinese nominal vs PPP GDP, see the following links:

https://en.wikipedia.org/wiki/List_of_countries_by_GDP_(nominal)

https://en.wikipedia.org/wiki/List_of_countries_by_GDP_(PPP)

So why use PPP at all?

PPP GDP

Because PPP does still play an important role in measuring "per-capita" GDP.

On a nominal basis U.S. per-capita GDP, or output per citizen, ranks #6 in the world at $85,373 (IMF) and is easily the highest of any country with any meaningful population (Monaco, the Caymans, Singapore, and even Ireland, all of which rank higher than the USA, are small countries with at most 5.9 million people).

China, which has far more people than the USA, falls to #69 at $13,136 on a per-capita basis (IMF). This is where the phrase “American workers are among the most productive in the world” comes from: the United States still produces a lot more valuable stuff per worker, and per citizen, than China and most other countries.

However, it still costs a lot less to live in China, so adjusting with PPP gives us a clearer picture of the material standard of living for a nation’s citizens. By nominal measure Americans produce 6.5 times more stuff per person than Chinese, but PPP tells us Americans don’t enjoy a 6.5 times higher living standard.

Using PPP, U.S. per-capita remains $85,373 but Chinese per-capita GDP rises to $25,015. So a more accurate picture of living standards tells us Americans are about 3.4 times richer than Chinese. Still a lot better, but not 6.5 times richer.

To see the difference in U.S./Chinese nominal vs PPP per-capita GDP, see the linked photos:

Per-capita GDP nominal

https://image.cnbcfm.com/api/v1/image/106859827-1616735644553-US-China_GDP_per_capita.png

Per-capita GDP PPP

https://mgmresearch.com/2018/12/China-vs-US-GDP-PPP-per-capita-comparison.png

Bottom line? When comparing how much one country produces against another, use nominal GDP.

When comparing how high a living standard one country’s citizens reap from economic production against another country’s citizens, use PPP per-capita GDP.

And ignore articles and charts that compare U.S. GDP to Chinese GDP using PPP metrics. They are meaningless when stacking two entire countries' economies next to one another.

One final complication about comparing countries. Nominal GDP is the best metric to use, but it’s not perfect.

U.S. GDP is measured in dollar spending on consumption, business investment, government purchases, and net exports. But, say… Japanese GDP is measured in yen spending on those same variables.

So we are now comparing a dollar-based metric with a yen-based metric, aka. apples and oranges.

To convert to an apples-to-apples comparison economists simply adjust by the going currency exchange rate. This is not a bad thing since, although the exchange rate fluctuates, currency markets adjust largely based on the perceived economic output of each country.

So if Japan were to go into a depression and produce 50% less stuff while leaving the money supply constant (leading to a doubling in prices) the Japanese nominal spending numbers might look like U.S. vs Japanese GDP hasn't changed much when in fact Japan’s real GDP is half what it was.

But currency markets would notice the Japanese inflation and the U.S. dollar would strengthen—by somewhere around double—against the yen. Hence Japan's dollar-denominated GDP would be halved (adjusted by a far more favorable exchange rate for the dollar) and in nominal terms U.S. GDP would accordingly look a whole lot bigger than Japan’s, and far bigger than it was a year prior.

Where this can lead to complications is central bank exchange rate manipulation. If a government is intervening in currency markets and manipulatively undervaluing its currency—something China did a great deal of 15-20 years ago and still does occasionally today—Chinese GDP would appear slightly smaller than it really is. This is why 15-20 years ago economists argued Chinese GDP was probably somewhat higher than the nominal numbers indicated.

Likewise if a country is overvaluing its currency, as Venezuela has for decades and Argentina did up to Javier Milei’s election victory, the currency adjustment will make Venezuelan or Argentinian GDP look stronger than they really are.

Yes, all along Venezuela's nominal GDP has been even worse than it appears, and that's before the socialist government starts lying.

In extreme cases like Venezuela and Argentina the resulting nominal GDP numbers were way off, but economists took into account the overvaluation and adjusted their GDP estimates to be more realistic. But in cases of modest undervaluation, such as China or Japan today, the GDP adjustment is pretty small.

Tuesday, September 17, 2024

GDP Part 2: How Much Does Government Spending Distort GDP Reports?

Click here to read the original Cautious Optimism Facebook post with comments

5 MIN READ - The Cautious Optimism Correspondent for Economic Affairs and Other Egghead Stuff discusses government spending’s effect on GDP.

In Part 1 we defined GDP as total spending in the economy, or consumer spending plus business investment spending plus government purchases—purchases, not transfers—plus net exports.

In mathematical terms GDP, or Y = C + I + G + Nx.

Many people notice that government spending (G) contributes to GDP and understandably wonder if GDP reports, particularly those that reflect strong economic growth, are inflated by it.

The short answer is: "Usually not by much, but there are some notable exceptions."

There are two major factors the public might not always take into account when formulating perceptions about government spending's role in GDP.

1) The first is that only government purchases are factored into GDP, not all government spending.

Which immediately excludes any spending that is simply direct transfers.

For example, Social Security is not included in GDP because the government isn’t really buying anything (although some might say votes) but instead taking money out of workers’ paychecks and transferring it into disability and retiree pension checks.

The same is true for welfare payments, unemployment checks, federal transfers to state and local governments, direct subsidies, and most notably interest on federal debt. None of it is factored into GDP.

In the end, only purchases are factored in.

Examples of government GDP purchase activity would include military procurement of weapons, maintenance parts and services, payments to contractors for building infrastructure and public works, or medical claims payments to purchase healthcare services and medicines for Medicare or Medicaid patients.

And government payrolls, which are considered “purchased services," are also included in GDP.

But once transfers are excluded the face of government spending changes significantly. For example, it may surprise some to learn that state and local government spending is actually a larger contributor to GDP than federal spending. The federal Departments of Transportation and Education may spend a lot of money, but much of it is simply transfers to state and local governments who in turn are the real purchasers of highway construction contracts, teacher salaries and schoolbooks, and even a great deal of medical spending.

State and local governments are also large spenders on salaries of state/city law enforcement, municipal transportation workers, social workers, etc… In 2023 there were over 19 million people employed by local and state governments versus just under 5 million by the federal government (including military).

In fact, even though defense spending is only about 15% of all federal spending, military purchases and payrolls represent 56% of all GDP purchases by the federal government. Which shows you just how much of federal purchases are defense-related and, more importantly, how so much more federal government spending above and beyond defense is simply redistributing money from taxpayers to someone else’s pocket.

And state and local government purchases are 68% higher than federal purchases.

2) The second factor is government’s contribution not to GDP, but to GDP growth.

In the most recent quarter (2Q24) government purchases constituted only 17.5% of GDP (as opposed to all government spending which is closer to 37% of GDP).

But even if one day the government ballooned to the point that purchases regularly became 50% of GDP, a government of that size  still wouldn’t necessarily inflate GDP growth.

The reason is in order to inflate GDP growth figures, the purchases themselves would have to grow much faster, beyond a big number like 50%.

To keep numbers simple, let’s say a $10 trillion GDP is comprised of $5 trillion in government purchases or 50%.

The following year GDP grows 3% to $10.3 trillion but let’s say government purchases remain $5 trillion which is still a huge share.

But since government purchases haven’t grown at all, none of the $300 billion or 3% in GDP growth can be attributed to government spending. In other words a huge government budget alone isn’t enough to push GDP growth up. Rather government purchases need to grow very rapidly.

This is why when a good GDP report comes out—say the recent Q2 revision to 3% annualized growth—one has to be careful about saying “Well all the growth is just government spending.” One first has to determine how much of the 3% growth was due to growth in government purchases.

And we have it for the last quarter. According to the BEA the economy grew at an annualized rate of 3% in Q2. Contributing to that figure was a 2.9% annualized increase in the largest component—consumer spending—a 7.5% annualized increase in business investment spending, and a 2.7% annualized increase in government purchases.

So at least in the case of Q2, government purchases grew slower than the private economy—both consumer and investment spending—and therefore can’t be argued to have artificially propped up GDP growth.

However during 2023 government purchases rose at a faster rate than overall GDP in four out of four quarters. So for the entire year, yes, government purchases can be blamed for propping up GDP growth although it would take more calculations to determine by how much.

And without question there are episodes in our history when government purchases have spiked so sharply that they have completely distorted GDP growth, making it look far stronger than it really is.

These episodes would be wars and, to a lesser degree, government stimulus packages.

The most extreme example is World War II when the federal government spent nearly half of GDP on purchases, mostly for war materiel and to pay for a near tenfold increase in federal employees (mostly military).

From 1941 to 1945 real GDP technically increased by an incredible 48.7%, seemingly an economic miracle after the Great Depression of the 1930’s.

But in fact the standard of living for Americans fell during the war with shortages of basic goods and draconian rationing.

This is reflected more accurately in GDP numbers when backing government purchases out—effectively looking at only private sector GDP.

From 1941 to 1945 GDP excluding government purchases actually contracted by 12.1%, and this from a baseline of the Great Depression. To put 12.1% in perspective, at the nadir of the 2008-09 Great Recession GDP is believed to have fallen about 4%.

The contraction in WWII private sector GDP is even worse when one considers U.S. population grew by 3.7% over the same period.

In a reverse extreme example there’s the single year period of 1945-46. In the year after the war GDP fell by 11.6%, a stunning contraction that dwarfed any single year in American history except for 1932.

So 1946 must have been the year of Great Depression 2.0, right?

No, it was the diametric opposite. GDP only contracted on paper because government cut back so sharply on war spending. In fact, the private sector absolutely boomed, reflected by a 42% upsurge in private GDP (a record) including a mindboggling 140% expansion in private business investment spending (another record).

This is how much government spending during a giant war can distort GDP growth. A major slump with low living standards can look like an unprecedented economic boom while a truly unprecedented boom can look like a terrible depression.

(All calculations are based on BEA historical statistics. Links to core data available upon request.)

A similar pattern, albeit on a smaller scale, holds true in the 1950-53 period during the Korean War.

And the Obama administration’s 2009 stimulus act also inflated GDP, albeit with even smaller effects than the Korean War. And even with higher government purchases GDP was still negative/recessionary—only less negative than it would have been without all of Obama’s deficit spending.

From Q1 of 2008 to Q1 of 2010 real GDP fell by about 1.6%, the recession bottoming out in Q2 or 2009. However in that same period federal government purchases rose by 12.6%.

To which liberal Keynesian economists argue “See, if the government hadn’t spent all that extra money GDP would have fallen more, meaning a deeper recession.”

Free market economists would counter that “Government spending and blowing money on cash for clunkers and other wasteful ‘shovel-ready’ projects doesn’t mean a stronger economy just because the dollar numbers can be added to a GDP ledger.”

But that’s another debate entirely.

In upcoming columns we’ll talk about annualized GDP, comparing GDP between countries, and a small GDP consumption vs. investment controversy.