No, it wasn't income inequality which was just a symptom of the real cause: bad monetary policy—this time with urging from Great Britain.
Click here to read the original Cautious Optimism Facebook post with comments
10 MIN READ - The Cautious Optimism Correspondent for Economic Affairs and other Egghead Stuff continues his series on the Great Depression addressing the pesky and poorly understood question of what started the whole sorry affair.
Click here to read the original Cautious Optimism Facebook post with comments
10 MIN READ - The Cautious Optimism Correspondent for Economic Affairs and other Egghead Stuff continues his series on the Great Depression addressing the pesky and poorly understood question of what started the whole sorry affair.
Meeting in the New York Federal Reserve Building, the heads
of the world’s four largest central banks convened to discuss a major policy
change in the new era of international monetary cooperation. Attending were:
Benjamin Strong—Governor of the New York Federal Reserve
Montagu Norman—Governor of the Bank of England
Hjalmar Schacht—Governor of the German Reichsbank
Charles Rist—Deputy Governor of the Bank of France
The American governor Strong and his British counterpart
Norman surprised their French and German opposite numbers with a startling
announcement: the Federal Reserve would launch an aggressive asset purchase and
quantitative easing campaign, effectively bolstering U.S. inflation in an
effort to curtail Great Britain’s chronic trade deficits with the United
States.
The meeting itself was a fait accompli, a mere formality
since the decision had long since been agreed upon between Strong and
Norman—close working associates and personal friends. Germany’s Schacht and
France’s Rist, hard-money advocates who preferred adherence to the traditional
workings of the pre-WWI classical gold standard with minimal state
interference, were shaken by the development which they viewed as potentially
destabilizing to the international monetary system. But powerless to do
anything about it they reluctantly agreed—at which point Strong turned to Rist
and excitedly proclaimed:
“I’m going to give a little coup de whiskey to the [U.S.] stock market!”
Strong kept his word. In the eighteen months that ensued the
Federal Reserve expanded its balance sheet from $1.175 billion to $1.824
billion—an increase of 55%—and the U.S. money supply ballooned at its fastest
rate of the entire 1920’s decade.
Newly created money and bank credit quickly spilled over
into asset markets and fueled speculation as the Dow Jones Industrial Average
advanced from an alltime high of 175.35 in early July 1927 to 386.10 in
September 1929, a stunning advance of over 120% in just 26 months. Real estate
speculation pushed commercial and particularly residential property prices into
record territory. Cheap credit spawned irrational business investment projects
such as factory overexpansion and competitive groundbreakings for “world’s
tallest building” in New York City.
And the rich (who by definition own assets) got a lot richer
while the poor (who by definition don’t own assets) saw only meager gains. Thus
wealth inequality—which today’s progressives are so obsessed with and claim in
and of itself causes recessions—widened due to the central bank induced inflow
of money. The climax of the Roaring Twenties was underway.
Oddly enough, since most of the new money flooded into asset
speculation the wholesale and consumer price indexes signaled subdued
inflation. Fooled by what appeared to be only moderate price pressures,
America’s greatest contemporary economist Irving Fisher concluded that the U.S.
economy had entered a new era of prosperity, famously declaring in the New York
Times that “Stock prices have reached what looks like a permanently high
plateau” on October 21, 1929—six days before the Black Tuesday crash.
Misled by holes in his own Quantity Theory of Money, it was
a mistake that Irving’s Monetarist successors would go on to make decades
later, including the great Milton Friedman himself who saw no inflation problems in 2005 and declared
"The stability of our economy is greater than it has ever been in our
history. We really are in remarkable shape.”
But back to the 1920’s. Benjamin Strong, who had always
suffered from poor health, died from tuberculosis in October of 1928 leaving it
to his successor George L. Harrison to wind up the Fed’s easing campaign at the
end of the year, tightening credit and raising interest rates in 1929. Starved
of plentiful new money to fuel the credit boom the economy began to sink into
recession by the summer of 1929, and dangerously overvalued asset market
bubbles began to burst, culminating with the famous stock market crash in
October.
The 1927 secret meeting is only known to us because Charles
Rist wrote of it in his personal diaries. And the Fed as policy culprit rings
with depressing familiarity of other such episodes in economic history. But the
story behind the 1927 Fed QE decision is truly unique among history’s
credit-induced tragedies. Its origins ultimately laid the groundwork that
dragged two continents into a cataclysmic monetary collapse that transformed
what should have been just another credit-fueled recession (in the tradition of
1819, 1825, 1837, 1857, 1873, 1893, 1907, and 1921) into the Great Depression.
And the ill-fated joint decision by the Federal Reserve and
Bank of England would prove so fatal that it would force the world off the
centuries-long venerable gold standard only a few short years later—ironically
because Strong and Norman attempted to “cheat” with policies that the
traditional gold standard would never have allowed.
This column tells that story, because it’s impossible to
truly understand what started the Great Depression and particularly why its
severity and duration were so unprecedented without grasping its unique
monetary policy origins.
II. BEFORE THE
ROARING TWENTIES: THE INTERNATIONAL CLASSICAL GOLD STANDARD
To understand why Great Britain asked for inflationary
assistance from the Federal Reserve in 1927 it’s essential to revisit the
global economy before 1914 when the industrialized world operated under the
19th century classical gold standard (roughly 1870-1914 with Britain first to
adopt it de jure in 1816 and the United States last in 1879).
Under the classical gold standard, every country’s currency
was defined as a unit weight of gold. For example, the U.S. dollar was not a
piece of paper but rather the dollar was literally about 1/20th an ounce of
gold—or 23.22 grains of gold to be exact. The British pound sterling was
defined as approximately 1/4th an ounce of gold or 113.00 grains. Francs,
marks, lira, etc… were also literally unit weights of gold. Paper banknotes and
demand deposit balances were simply claims on dollars, pounds, francs, etc… hence
why old banknotes of the 19th century bore the promise “Will pay the bearer on
demand five dollars.”
Because both the dollar and the pound were defined as unit
weights of gold, the “exchange rate” between the two was fixed. And since one
pound sterling contained 4.86 times more gold than one dollar, the pound
sterling equaled $4.86—an exchange rate that had been unchanged since the U.S.
Coinage Act of 1834.
Another important attribute of the classical gold standard
was that any institution that issued paper banknotes or demand deposit balances
(usually created when that institution loaned money) was obligated to convert
those notes or deposits on demand in gold coin. In the U.S. that commonly meant
gold eagle coins equal to $20 in gold, or in Britain the gold sovereign
containing one pound sterling equivalent in gold. Other countries’ currencies
followed the same rules.
The constant threat of on-demand redemption by all holders
of paper liabilities was critical as it kept issuing institutions “honest.” That
is, whether they were commercial banks—as was the case in the USA and Canada—or
central banks such as the Bank of England, the threat of redemption served as a
natural check against overissuance or overexpansion of credit.
The handful of pre-WWI examples of irresponsible
overexpansion by banks were virtually always the consequence of government
intervention overturning private redemption contracts such as legally
suspending gold convertibility (Great Britain during the Napoleonic Wars
1797-1825, USA during the War of 1812 from 1812-1815) or attempts to substitute
government paper for gold (USA: “Greenback” paper money during the Civil War).
But in the relatively free and undisturbed periods of money and banking,
institutions were kept in check by market forces that prevented inflationary
overexpansion.
The same rules applied to entire nations. If one country’s
commercial banks or central bank printed too many banknotes or created too much
demand deposit checkbook money (ie. inflation), prices would rise in that
country and, given fixed exchange rates, competing imported products became
cheaper. Consumers in the inflating country would buy more imports, sending
their currency (say in this case, British pounds) overseas. The receiving
country (say, France) had little use for pounds and would submit them for
redemption to the Bank of England and gold would flow across the Channel.
With its gold reserves diminishing, the British banking
system would be forced to end its overexpansion or even contract, and prices
would fall back into line. Conversely, with French gold reserves rising the
resulting increase the money supply would make French products more expensive
leading to higher British imports and an equilibrium would ensue.
Scottish philosopher David Hume observed this phenomenon and
wrote about it in the 1750’s. The tendency for freely moving international
commerce to put a check on overexpansion of money and credit vis-à-vis a
country’s gold reserves has been known since as the Hume price-specie-flow mechanism.
And under this self-regulating international monetary system—even with
occasional destabilizing interventions by governments—the world saw an
explosion in wealth creation and international trade. For example worldwide
foreign investment rose from 7% of GDP in 1870 to 18% of GDP in 1914 (NBER:
Estevadeordal, Frantz, Taylor). That’s a near tripling not of foreign
investment, but of its share of world GDP. Since world GDP rose by
approximately 147% during the same period (A. Madison), total foreign investment
rose by 530% in just 44 years.
The same is true of total world trade. From 1870 to 1914
global trade rose from 10% of GDP to 21%, or in absolute terms an increase of
419%. And these gains were accompanied by a dramatic decline in major European wars
during the latter half of the 19th century and early 20th century.
No comments:
Post a Comment
Note: Only a member of this blog may post a comment.